Okay, let’s
start from the premise that, by most US standards, I would probably be
considered way left of center. In fact, just about any time I read a statement
by Professor Noam Chomsky—perhaps America’s most eminent left-winger—regarding
social ethics and values, I can barely contain my applause and find myself
thinking, “Couldn’t have said it better myself!” (No surprise, since Professor
Chomsky is, among many other things, one of the world’s foremost experts in
linguistics). I mean I’m not talking armed-revolution Che Guevara leftist, but
certainly far enough left that if the far-right choir boys like O’Reilly,
Limbaugh and Beck were to read my comments, they might certainly refer to me as
“a leftwing loon” (just as I might consider them overpaid mouthpieces for
corporate fascism and pandering stooges to the me-first wealth-hoarders that
comprise the nefarious upper one percent).
But here in
Argentina, I’ve quite often been considered (accused of being) just the opposite,
a “gorilón” (literally ‘big
gorilla’), the term used to describe defenders of US-type political and
economic ideals (the other catch-all term here for anything the slightest bit
Yankee is “neo-liberal” and it is frequently spat out like a cuss word), which
are widely considered to be synonymous with economic and cultural imperialism
and overall exploitation of the working class. Gorilón is also the epithet attached to just about anyone who
doesn’t toe the line of the majority Peronist Party, and certainly anyone who
is an opponent of the current Kirchner regime. (Guilty as charged).
Somewhere
in between these two caricature-like descriptions lies the truth about me. I am
clearly liberal, but try, above all, to see each situation from an individual viewpoint
and issue the most objective opinion I can, within the limits of “objectivity”
that each person’s own background, education and life experience permit. Which
is probably why, when I received an invitation from a Facebook friend to “like”
a group that supports workers’ taking over bankrupt firms they once worked for
and turning them into worker cooperatives, I was immediately in two (or more)
minds about it. I couldn’t “like” it, but neither could I rule out situations
in which I would consider it a positive possibility for serious consideration.
What concerned me most was where the idea of how this might be done was coming
from, and it was coming from my own backyard, in Argentina.
In her
all-encompassing arrogance and lack of self-assessment, Argentina’s President
Cristina Kirchner, on more than one occasion, during her first term in office,
suggested that Western leaders, including US President Barack Obama, might be
taking their cue from her and her late husband (and president before her), Néstor
Kirchner, in dealing with their own political and economic crises. Considering
the state of impending and ongoing political and economic crisis which has
accompanied her in the first year of her second term as a result of her
autocratic, devil-may-care brand of governance, such suggestions seem ever more
delusional, especially considering how legal insecurity in Argentina has grown
in almost direct proportion to the Kirchner administration’s penchant for
holding onto power at any cost.
In the
trickle-down from that kind of contempt for the hard and fast rules of
democracy regarding basic tenets of freedom and justice, one of the institutions
that has suffered some serious blows—through land occupations, government
takeovers, etc.—has been respect for private property. So when I read that the international co-op
group in question was, indeed (and incredibly) following the lead of cooperatives
formed in Argentina after workers took over the installations of the bankrupt
former employers, it set off alarm bells.
What’s a Co-op? A cooperative (or co-op) is, simply defined, an
independent association of people who decide to cooperate with each other for mutual benefit. Co-ops can act as
non-profits in strictly social or cultural endeavors, but most often are economic
institutions, nearly always based originally on some social need.
The idea of
the cooperative is certainly nothing new. It’s basically a throwback to ancient
tribal governance, in which so-called “primitive peoples” set up a cooperative order for their societies, a
more or less (depending on the tribe) “pecking order” by which to allot jobs, duties,
resources, etc., and so, maintain the peace, harmony and security of their social
groups. Actual “trade” was largely external (‘non-domestic’), probably based on
internal surplus and external requirements, and was for the mutual profit of
the tribe. Or that is, at least, the popular anthropological theory.
This was,
however, no accident or mere stroke of luck. What was different about the
Rochdale Society, in comparison with failed co-op ventures of earlier years,
was that it had a strong “franchise model” based on a set of hard and fast
rules for mutual cooperation that its founders laid down from the outset. These
rules were called The Rochdale Principles.
Some of the more salient premises of the Rochdale pact that survive today in
what are considered sound bases for the establishment of successful co-ops
include: open membership and general non-discriminatory treatment, motivation
and rewards, democratic governance through member control, member economic
participation, autonomy and independence in the co-op’s governance and
operations, information transparency, provision of education and training to
members, cooperation with other cooperatives, and general concern for the
community.
Eli Whitney, father of the Industrial Revolution |
In more
modern eras there have been hundreds of examples of cooperative-type social
structures, but the one that is considered a classic early example of a highly successful
co-op is the Rochdale Society of
Equitable Pioneers. The Rochdale
Society was established in England in 1844. Like the globalization, computerization
and robotics trends that are today forcing so many downsized workers to have to
seek other alternatives for making a living, the nineteenth-century Industrial
Revolution was doing the same thing to many of the manufacturing workers and
artisans of those times. Also like many of the unemployed workers of today, who
once thought their competencies would provide them with a way to make a good
living for the rest of their lives, many skilled workers and tradesmen in the
times of the Industrial Revolution also found themselves, all of the sudden,
grossly underemployed and impoverished. The founding core of the Rochdale
Society was made up of about thirty such workers around a third of whom were
weavers downsized by the industrial age inventions of the likes of American Eli
Whitney (1765-1825) and other stars of the industrialization era. (By the way,
after inventing the cotton gin and a viable textile milling machine, Whitney
himself got “downsized” through patent infringement and spent the rest of his
days applying the idea of “interchangeable parts” that he had long championed
to making standardized firearms and selling them to the US government for its
Continental Army).
Like many
other people put out of work by the newfangled equipment of the
industrialization craze, the Rochdale Society wasn’t a union or guild bent on
taking back what it had lost as a skilled labor force, but simply a cooperative
group of individuals pooling their mental and (meager) financial resources to try
and figure out how to survive in a world that had dealt them a raw and
unappreciative hand. So their founding idea was a simple one: to combine their
resources in such a way as to permit them to buy basic food items that they
could no longer individually afford to purchase from middlemen. The method they
finally struck upon was not only buying enough for themselves, but also enough
to sell and thus pay for their own consumer needs. Each managed to scrape together
£1.00 to buy into the venture, and, just before Christmas, opened a tiny shop
with a very limited but affordable supply of sugar, butter, flour, oatmeal and
candles to sell to the working public.
Why it Worked. First conceived as a mere survival tactic, the
idea nevertheless quickly caught on in such a way as to make the Rochdale
cooperative a sort of Industrial Revolution-style Mickey D’s. Within a very
short time the co-op’s stores began to also stock more expensive high-quality items
like tea and tobacco. And within a few short years, England saw the emergence
of hundreds, and then, over a thousand cooperatives based on the Rochdale
model.
The first Rochdale co-op store. Photo by Sacrletharlot69 via Wikipedia. |
Since that
time co-ops of all kinds—from farming and electric power to finance and
entrepreneurial—have been formed and have tended to have a better general track
record for stability and endurance than any other type of business. Reliable
studies have shown that the survival rate for new businesses in certain major
economies beyond their first ten years is only about two in ten, while co-ops
fair far better at four in ten. And what is, perhaps, most important about them
is the self-determination that is at their core: They frequently—if not
always—fill a need that neither business nor government has been willing or
capable of filling. So it is that co-ops have brought such standard of living
improvements as electric power, telecommunications, cheap financing and
agricultural marketing and trade to segments of society which would otherwise
have remained relegated to a more backward existence for much longer, because
of where they ranked on the list of institutional priorities.
In my
native United States, in the years since World War II, the Cold War Red
Scare—in which anti-communist witch-hunts were rife—and the advent of extreme
corporate capitalism and its unhealthy influence on government following the
fall of the Berlin Wall, have often given cooperatives a bad rap, mostly
because of paranoia about their being based
on the premise of economic democracy, which is all about fair
distribution of wealth, and which is often erroneously equated with some sinister
Marxist plot to destroy capitalism. It is actually a philosophy that has to do
with taking economic decision-making out of the hands of a tiny élite of
corporate shareholders and putting it into the hands of a much broader segment
of real stakeholders, which makes it not the enemy of, but an alternative to a
system that, of late, has shown serious signs of failure.
Pros and Cons. Anyway, enough with Co-ops 101: What we’re interested in here are worker cooperatives,
in which, basically, an enterprise is owned and operated by those who actually
produce what it makes. If that were the plan for a business starting from
scratch in today’s highly entrepreneurial world, I would be all for it since,
ideally, the cooperative system tends to foster a lot of things that big
business is only just now learning about, after decades of arm-twisting and
foot-dragging: things like cutting waste, assuming full accountability to the
actual owners (the shareholders) and to the surrounding community, social
commitment, respect for worker rights, social inclusion, product quality
improvement for reasons other than increased profits and legal impositions, and
so on, as well as the loyalty of the capital involved to the place where it is
produced (i.e., a cooperative doesn’t just shut down operations in, say, Ohio
or Texas, or North Carolina, in order to reopen them in a maquiladora on the opposite
side of the Río Grande, where it can get away with exploiting cheap labor,
abysmal working atmospheres and much lower environmental standards. Nor does it
have fat cat executives pulling down multi-million-dollar pay packages plus
sumptuous perks at the top.
But that
wasn’t the proposal that came my way via Facebook.
Working World. The cause I was requested to “like” by my Facebook
friend was that of The Working World. And let me just say that, right off the
bat, I was indeed tempted to click the LIKE button. The Working World describes
itself as “a non-profit organization that
provides investment capital and technical support for worker cooperatives using
an innovative finance model.” The group explains how its model works as follows: “We
support worker cooperatives using a finance model that puts money at the
service of people, not the other way around. We help design, fund, and carry
out productive projects, only requiring that cooperatives pay us back with the
revenues the investments generate. As active partners, we are more motivated to
ensure that these projects are successful, or in other words, that finance is
only used as a tool to create real, lasting wealth for those that it serves.
Upon return, all investment money is reintegrated to our locally-based
revolving loan fund to be overseen by the cooperatives and the community it
serves.”
So far, so good. But delving deeper
into the little I could find out about the organization, I came across some
articles regarding its work in the United States and the world. What
particularly grabbed my attention was one posted by Steve Wong on the group’s
blog in which he praised certain co-op operations that he had observed on a
trip to Argentina to visit Working World affiliates (or potential affiliates).
These were, according to the author of the article, “recovered businesses”
which Wong describes as follows: “For
those who don’t know, the recovered businesses began as bankrupt companies that
were occupied and reopened by workers after the Argentine economic crisis in
2001. While their paths have been difficult and fraught with challenges, as a
movement these cooperatives have succeeded, going out of business less
frequently than their traditional counterparts and serving as important anchors
of employment in local communities throughout Argentina.”
The question here, however, isn’t
whether or not the resulting worker co-ops have done a better job than their
former employers in operating their businesses, but of how they got those
businesses in the first place. And it is worthy of concern that The Working
World seems to consider the Argentine “model” one that might well be worthy of
replication elsewhere. “Occupation” models are a hallmark, for instance, of the
current governing movement that has ruled the country for the past decade. And
political as well as economic motives have been cited for at least one of the
worker occupations that the group mentions: the fact that the factory in question
was started in the late 1970s under the former military regime taking advantage
of incentives the de facto government offered, and that its owner also took
advantage of backing from the later democratic administration of Carlos Menem,
the corruption and failed privatizations of which have made it a frequent
target in the current administration’s efforts to buoy its own popularity
levels.
But the point is not how inept or
corrupt the former owners of occupied properties might have been. These are
only sad or scandalous anecdotes in the process that led to their failure. What
is indeed important is that any “model” that encourages the hostile takeover of
private property is a dangerous precedent and one that can easily play into the
power games of governments which don’t respect the law or the basic rules of
democracy either.
Clearly, with what we know now about
the kind of corporate corruption that has led to the world crisis that first
broke in 2007, the rules of how business is done have to change. And this is
also true of the noxious effects that globalization has fostered in terms of
undermining worker rights and the democratic health of labor unions. But transformation
needs to come through democratic channels, by encouraging, lobbying for, and
demanding changes in the laws that govern business—with one such change being
the placement of workers at the top of the list of a company’s creditors, so as
to give them the legal clout necessary to negotiate such takeovers, while
respecting the property rights of the former owner. If de facto takeovers of
bankrupt businesses become the norm, then it is only one small step to
businesses (and other sorts of private property) being snatched from their
owners’ hands on the strength of any excuse at all, and that, to an autocratic populist
government like Argentina’s current one, which has repeatedly demonstrated its
bent for ignoring the law in this respect, would be a powerful temptation in
dealing with its political enemies in business.
1 comment:
All too often, the epilogue of takeovers in Argentina involves the demand for government subsidy to protect employment, regardless of whether the enterprise is viable. We have seen too much of that, cynically pursued by politicians of all denominations.
Cooperatives are a valid alternative as is any contractual arrangement between free and willing participants.
Post a Comment